Reinhart and Rogoff have a series of working papers (here) analysing the key features of financial crises, using data over many centuries and from around the world. In their papers 2008a and 2008b (here and here) they highlight two common characteristics of banking crises: 1. they are usually followed by severe government deficits, but the relationship is not caused by bank bailout costs; the direct costs of bank bailouts are swamped by recession-related tax shortfalls and expenditure increases, 2. banking crises are sometimes followed by sovereign defaults, but again it is not due to direct costs of bank failures including bailout costs, since these are not typically a substantial part of the government budget crisis.
In another one of this series of papers, 2007 (here) they demonstrate the prevalence and wide ubiquity of sovereign debt crises. They stress that sovereign debt crises are not confined to less developed countries. The small number of sovereign debt crises in developed Western countries since WWII is a typical trough in the cycle, which by historical patterns is due to end soon.
Looking around the world and acknowledging the historical patterns shown in their paper, a hidden message of the paper (in my own subjective reading) is that the Euro zone is due for at least one sovereign debt default in the next decade. Will it be Ireland, and what can be done to prevent such a disaster?
Rossa White of Davy Stockbrokers argues (here) that quote “the risk of Ireland not being able to meet ongoing debt payments over the next few years is very low.” The credit default swap market seems to disagree. The most recent Ireland government bond CDS rate is 3.41% meaning that institutional investor are paying 3.41% to receive the shortfall on par value when and if Irish government bonds default. If the payment shortfall on default is 50% (a typical disastrous sovereign default) this is equivalent to a risk-neutral per-year default probability of 3.41%/.5 = 6.82%. Over five years this aggregates to a cumulative default probability of (1- (1-.0682)^5)=28.09%. Of course investors are not risk neutral so there is a substantial risk premium in the CDS rate, but still this indicates a non-negligible true probability of default reflected in market rates.
Ireland must make policy changes to set the probability of sovereign default close to zero. There is an over-emphasis on dealing with the problems in the banking industry as a solution to the current economic crisis. Going forward, dealing with public finances is at least as important, probably much more important.
The relative ordering of policy priorities is relevant since there is a finite supply of political capital to address the current crisis. If all of the political capital is spent on the least important problems, the most important ones will go unsolved. That increases the medium-term risk of a true disaster: a sovereign debt default. An article in the Irish Times by Stephen Collins, “The Real Danger is in Political Stalemate as the Roof Falls In,” is disquieting reading (here).
The two crucial intermediate policy goals are broadening and deepening the net tax take from households, and lowering the cost of public services. The proposed 10% levy on public service pensions is an admirable first start on the second of these goals. The recent political weakening of the government, in the face of continuing revelations about banking industry shenanigans, has endangered this important first step. Does the present government have enough political capital to face up to raising taxes on middle earners?
Another policy goal is to decrease economic policy uncertainty, so that businesses and households can plan and invest. Mervyn King stresses the importance of economic policy predictability and stability (wittily stated here). He quips that one of his policy goals as head of the Bank of England is to be extremely boring. Presumably this comes easy to him as a well-trained economist. There is also a wealth of evidence that the reason inflation lowers growth is that it creates planning uncertainty for businesses and consumers, see for example Huizinga 1993 (here). Irish businesses and households are not facing price turbulence but rather government policy turbulence, which can be even worse. The Irish government needs to make hard policy choices, state clearly that it intends to enact them fully, and then do so reliably.